The trouble with financial bubbles (2024)

Very soon after the magnitude of the 2008 financial crisis became clear, a lively debate began about whether central banks and regulators could – and should – have done more to head it off. The traditional view, notably shared by the former US Federal Reserve chairman, Alan Greenspan, is that any attempt to prick financial bubbles in advance is doomed to failure. The most central banks can do is clean up the mess.

Bubble pricking may indeed choke off growth unnecessarily – and at high social cost. But there is a counter-argument. Economists at the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) have maintained that the costs of the crisis were so large, and the cleanup so long, that we should surely now look for ways to act pre-emptively when we again see a dangerous buildup of liquidity and credit.

Hence the fierce (albeit arcane and polite) dispute between the two sides at the International Monetary Fund’s recent meeting in Lima, Peru. For the literary minded, it was reminiscent of Jonathan Swift’s Gulliver’s Travels. Gulliver finds himself caught in a war between two tribes, one of which believes that a boiled egg should always be opened at the narrow end, while the other is fervent in its view that a spoon fits better into the bigger, rounded end.

China should avoid financial meltdownRead more

It is fair to say that the debate has moved on a little since 2008. Most important, macroprudential regulation has been added to policymakers’ toolkit: simply put, it makes sense to vary banks’ capital requirements according to the financial cycle. When credit expansion is rapid, it may be appropriate to increase banks’ capital requirements as a hedge against the heightened risk of a subsequent contraction. This increase would be above what microprudential supervision – assessing the risks to individual institutions – might dictate. In this way, the new Basel rules allow for requiring banks to maintain a so-called countercyclical buffer of extra capital.

But if the idea of the countercyclical buffer is now generally accepted, what of the “nuclear option” to prick a bubble: is it justifiable to increase interest rates in response to a credit boom, even though the inflation rate might still be below target? And should central banks be given a specific financial-stability objective, separate from an inflation target?

Jaime Caruana, the general manager of the BIS and a former governor of the Bank of Spain, answers yes to both questions. In Lima, he argued that the so-called “separation principle”, whereby monetary and financial stability are addressed differently and tasked to separate agencies, no longer makes sense.

The two sets of policies are, of course, bound to interact; but Caruana argues that it is wrong to say that we know too little about financial instability to be able to act in a pre-emptive way. We know as much about bubbles as we do about inflation, Caruana argues, and the need of central banks to move interest rates for reasons other than the short-term control of consumer-price trends should be explicitly recognised.

At the Lima meeting, the traditionalist counterview came from Benoît Cœuré of the European Central Bank. A central bank, he argued, needs a very simple mandate that allows it to explain its actions clearly and be held accountable for them. So let central banks stick to the separation principle, “which makes our life simple. We do not want a complicated set of objectives.”

For Cœuré, trying to maintain financial stability is in the “too difficult” box. Even macroprudential regulation is of dubious value: supervisors should confine themselves to overseeing individual institutions, leaving macro-level policy to the grownups.

Nemat Shafik, a deputy governor of the Bank of England, tried to position herself between these opposing positions. She proposed relying on three lines of defence against financial instability.

Microprudential regulation, she argued, is the first line of defence: if all banks are lending prudently, the chances of collective excesses are lower. But the second line of defence is macroprudential manipulation of capital requirements, to be applied across the board or to selected market segments, such as mortgages. And, if all else fails to achieve financial stability, central banks could change interest rates. Because British law assigns capital regulation and interest-rate policy to two separate committees – with different members – within the Bank of England, the Shafik strategy would require some clever political and bureaucratic manoeuvring.

Industrial quantities of research, analysis and debate have been devoted to the causes of the 2008 crisis and its consequences; so it seems odd that senior central bankers are still so sharply divided on the central issue of financial stability. All those days spent in secret conclave in Basel, drinking through the BIS’s legendary wine cellar, have apparently led to no consensus.

My view is that Caruana had the best of the arguments in Lima, and Cœuré the worst. Sticking to a simple objective in the interests of a quiet life, even if you know it to be imperfect, is an inelegant posture at best. We need our central bankers to make complex decisions and to be able to balance potentially conflicting objectives. We accept that they will not always be right. However, it is surely incumbent on them to learn from the biggest financial meltdown of the last 80 years, rather than to press on, regardless, with policy approaches that so signally failed.

Howard Davies, the first chairman of the United Kingdom’s Financial Services Authority, is chairman of the Royal Bank of Scotland. He has been director of the London School of Economics, deputy governor of the Bank of England and director general of the Confederation of British Industry.

Copyright: Project Syndicate 2015

The trouble with financial bubbles (2024)

FAQs

What is the main problem with a bubble? ›

Because speculative demand, rather than intrinsic worth, fuels the inflated prices, the bubble eventually but inevitably pops, and massive sell-offs cause prices to decline, often quite dramatically. In most cases, in fact, a speculative bubble is followed by a spectacular crash in the securities in question.

What are the effects of economic bubbles? ›

Once the bubble bursts, the fall in prices causes the collapse of unsustainable investment schemes (especially speculative and/or Ponzi investments, but not exclusively so), which leads to a crisis of consumer (and investor) confidence that may result in a financial panic and/or financial crisis.

What is the financial bubble? ›

A bubble is an economic cycle that is characterized by the rapid escalation of market value, particularly in the price of assets. This fast inflation is followed by a quick decrease in value, or a contraction, that is sometimes referred to as a "crash" or a "bubble burst."

What happens when an asset bubble bursts? ›

Eventually, however, the bubble bursts. As the price of the asset comes down, investment may decrease and the economy may contract.

What are the five stages of the financial bubble? ›

In his 1986 book, Stabilizing an Unstable Economy, economist Hyman P. Minsky identified the five stages to a credit cycle – displacement, boom, euphoria, profit-taking, and panic.

What happens when the debt bubble bursts? ›

If the corporate debt bubble bursts, the bonds would be repriced, resulting in a massive loss by the mutual funds, high-yield funds, pension funds, and endowments with corporate bond assets.

Do bubbles cause inflation? ›

The economy starts out with fixed prices. The interest rate is low. A stochastic monetary bubble grows that diverts savings from investment. At a stopping time at which firms coordinate on adjusting their prices, the bubble bursts, inflation picks up, and both nominal and real rates increase.

Why are financial markets prone to bubbles? ›

An economic bubble occurs when asset values rise above their true value. The reasons behind such bubbles are numerous and complicated. People have more money to invest when the economy is expanding, and salaries are rising. This rise in investment demand has the potential to push up asset prices and create a bubble.

What are the biggest economic bubbles in the world? ›

Here are five examples of historic speculative bubbles: the Dutch Tulipmania (1634-1638); the Mississippi Bubble (1719-1720); the South Sea Bubble (1720); the Bull Market of the Roaring Twenties (1924-1929); and Japan's "Bubble Economy" of the 1980s.

What is the bursting of financial bubbles? ›

Rapid price rise: Prices shoot up very rapidly during a bubble, often at an unsustainable pace. Crash: The bubble is said to burst when prices plummet dramatically, eroding much of the wealth that had been accumulated during the bubble phase.

How long can a financial bubble last? ›

Data from the eight most prominent such events in history reveals that an economic, asset, market bubble lasts for about 5.6 years or about 67.5 months.

When did the financial bubble burst? ›

The dot-com bubble burst in March 2000, with the technology heavy NASDAQ Composite index peaking at 5,048.62 on March 10 (5,132.52 intraday), more than double its value just a year before. By 2001, the bubble's deflation was running full speed.

What are the risks of asset bubbles? ›

This leads to further speculation and further price increases not supported by market fundamentals. The mere expectation of future price appreciation in the bubble assets drives buyers to bid prices higher. The resulting flood of investment dollars into the asset pushes the price to even more inflated levels.

How to prevent economic bubbles? ›

Regulating leverage would help to prevent misallocation of resources from asset bubbles. The leverage ratio requirement would only be applied to debt-based financing across the financial system. This excludes entities or activities that are fully or largely financed by equity, such as mutual or investment funds.

What was the first financial bubble? ›

'Tulipmania' as it is known today is generally cited as being the first example of an economic, or financial bubble. The tulip was introduced to the Dutch via Ottoman Empire traders.

What is the main problem with a bubble quizlet? ›

The real problem with bursting bubbles is that it opens up the possibility of something worse: a financial meltdown and that can cause a depression.

How bad are bubbles for the environment? ›

But it's a major concern when the particles it carries are potentially hazardous: bubbles caught in a crashing wave can send vaporized microplastics into the air where they might mess with the Earth's atmosphere; bubbles burst by a flushing toilet can fling bacteria meters and onto nearby surfaces; a frothing cruise ...

What causes a bubble to collapse? ›

The reason is that as soon as the hole forms, trapped gas can escape from the bubble. Without the support of this gas, the forces on the liquid film become unbalanced, causing the bubble to collapse and radial wrinkles to form around the bubble's edge – rather like what happens in an elastic sheet, or a parachute.

What is a bubble and what causes it? ›

Key Takeaways. A bubble is an economic cycle that is characterized by the rapid escalation of market value, particularly in the price of assets. This steep price rise is typically followed by a rapid decrease in value, or a contraction, when the bubble is burst.

Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Terrell Hackett

Last Updated:

Views: 6090

Rating: 4.1 / 5 (72 voted)

Reviews: 95% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Terrell Hackett

Birthday: 1992-03-17

Address: Suite 453 459 Gibson Squares, East Adriane, AK 71925-5692

Phone: +21811810803470

Job: Chief Representative

Hobby: Board games, Rock climbing, Ghost hunting, Origami, Kabaddi, Mushroom hunting, Gaming

Introduction: My name is Terrell Hackett, I am a gleaming, brainy, courageous, helpful, healthy, cooperative, graceful person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.