The granular origins of exchange-rate fluctuations – Bank Underground (2024)

Simon Lloyd, Daniel Ostry and Balduin Bippus

The granular origins of exchange-rate fluctuations – Bank Underground (1)

How much capital flows move exchange rates is a central question in international macroeconomics. A major challenge to addressing it has been the difficulty identifying exogenous cross-border flows, since flows and exchange rates can evolve simultaneously with factors like risk sentiment. In this post, we summarise a staff working paper that resolves this impasse using bank-level data capturing the external positions of UK-based global intermediaries to construct novel ‘Granular Instrumental Variables‘ (GIVs). Using these GIVs, we find that banks’ United States dollar (USD) demand is inelastic – a 1% increase in net-dollar assets appreciates the dollar by 2% against sterling – state dependent – effects double when banks’ capital ratios are one standard deviation below average – and that banks are a ‘marginal investor’ in the dollar-sterling market.

Our bank-level data set

To reach these conclusions, we use a detailed data set that captures, at a quarterly frequency from 1997 to 2019, the cross-border assets and liabilities of global banks – both UK and foreign-owned ones – which are based in the UK. Two features of our data set make it particularly well-suited to assess the causal effects of international banking flows on the USD.

First, owing to the UK’s position as the world’s largest international financial centre, our data covers a large share of international flows – both in absolute terms and relative to other studies. Specifically, it captures over 38% of the UK’s total external asset position over our 1997–2019 sample, and over 5% of overall global cross-border positions. Moreover, in comparison to lending in other financial centres, cross-border lending by UK-resident banks stands out, as Chart 1 shows. In particular, cross-border lending by UK-based banks comprises, on average, almost one fifth of total cross-border bank claims over the 1997–2019 period. So, our data is representative of both UK and global cross-border borrowing and lending.

Chart 1: The extent of UK-resident banks’ cross-border claims

The granular origins of exchange-rate fluctuations – Bank Underground (2)

Notes: Aggregate cross-border banking claims, for the UK and other selected countries, 1997 Q1–2019 Q3.

Source: BIS Locational Banking Statistics.

Second, our data set reveals that cross-border lending and borrowing by global banks is concentrated among a relatively small number of large financial players. Specifically, in our sample of 451 banks that take positions in USDs, we observe that banks’ cross-border lending satisfies the Pareto principle: around 20% of global banks hold 80% of cross-border USD positions. Chart 2 presents this fact graphically by plotting Lorenz curves and associated Gini coefficients for cross-border USD assets (both debt and equity) of UK-resident banks as well as for cross-border deposit liabilities. Overall, this heterogeneity in the size of global banks is suggestive of ‘granularity‘ in cross-border borrowing and lending.

Chart 2: The granularity of UK-resident banks’ cross-border claims

The granular origins of exchange-rate fluctuations – Bank Underground (3)

Notes: Lorenz curves and Gini coefficients for global banks’ average cross-border debt assets, equity assets and deposit liabilities in 2019 Q2. The 45-degree line reflects a hypothetical Lorenz curve in which all banks have an equal amount of cross-border positions and the Gini coefficient is 0.

Our Granular Instrumental Variables (GIVs)

We exploit the substantial variation in the size of banks’ cross-border USD positions to construct GIVs as exogenous variation in aggregate capital flows.

The idea behind our GIVs is to construct a time-series of exogenous cross-border capital flows from a panel of bank-level capital flows by extracting only the idiosyncratic moves by large banks. For this to work, some banks must be sufficiently large that their flows, in response to an exogenous shock, influence aggregate capital flows – ie, they are relevant. As discussed above, we find clear evidence for this in the data. Second, we require that both large and small banks respond in similar ways to unobserved aggregate shocks. This is because we construct our GIVs as the difference between the USD flows by large banks – formally, the size-weighted average of banks’ flows – and the USD flows of average banks – ie, the equal-weighted average of banks’ flows. The GIVs can then be treated as exogenous insofar as subtracting away the equal-weighted average strips out the common shocks driving banks’ capital flows. In this case, what remains are the idiosyncratic flows in and out of USD assets by large banks, which implies our GIVs are both valid for aggregate flows and exogenous.

As evidence for this exogeneity, and – as other papers have shown – unlike many other instruments used in the literature, we show that our GIVs are uncorrelated with proxies for the Global Financial Cycle. Furthermore, a narrative check of our GIVs reveals that the lion’s share of moves are driven, as expected, by idiosyncratic shocks to large banks, such as management changes, mergers or legal penalties, as well as stress-test failings and computer-system failures.

Three key empirical results

Controlling for a wide array of bank-level and aggregate factors, we use our GIVs to estimate the causal links between capital flows and exchange rates empirically. We emphasise three key results.

First, we find that changes in UK-based global banks’ net USD positions – ie, when the stock of USD-denominated external assets changes relative to the stock of USD-denominated external liabilities – have a significant causal effect on the USD/GBP exchange rate. Specifically, by regressing exchange-rate movements directly on our net dollar-debt GIV , we find that a 1% increase in UK-resident banks’ net dollar-debt position leads to a 0.4%–0.8% appreciation of the USD against GBP on impact. These effects persist too. Using a local-projections specification, we estimate that this shock results in around a 2% cumulative USD appreciation one year after the shock, as Chart 3 demonstrates. Consistent with theory, this effect does not reverse even two years after the initial shock.

Chart 3: Dynamic effects of exogenous changes in net USD debt positions on the USD/GBP exchange rate

The granular origins of exchange-rate fluctuations – Bank Underground (4)

Notes: Increase denotes appreciation of USD (depreciation of GBP) in response to 1% shock to USD positions. Shaded area denotes 95% confidence band.

Second, we use our GIVs to estimate the slopes of the supply curve for USDs from rest of the world investors – such as hedge funds and mutual funds, the focus of Camanho et al (2022) – and the demand curve for USDs by UK-resident global banks using two-stage least squares. On the supply side, we find that USD supply from the rest of the world is elastic with respect to the USD/GBP exchange rate. Otherwise stated, the supply curve for dollars by non-UK bank intermediaries is relatively flat: a 1% exchange-rate change results in a more than proportional change in the supply of USDs. However, on the demand side, our estimates reveal that USD demand by UK-resident banks is inelastic, that is, the demand curve is relatively steep. Chart 4 presents the estimated demand and supply relationships graphically.

Chart 4: Inelastic UK-bank demand for and elastic rest of the world supply of USDs

The granular origins of exchange-rate fluctuations – Bank Underground (5)

Notes: Supply and demand relationships between the change in the exchange rate and changes in net USD-denominated debt quantities implied by elasticity estimates. Shaded areas denote one standard deviation error bands.

Third, to investigate the drivers of this inelastic demand, we extend our empirical setup to investigate the role of banks’ time-varying risk-bearing capacity for FX dynamics. Interacting banks’ Tier-1 capital ratios with our GIVs suggests that the causal effect of capital flows on exchange rates is twice as large when banks’ capital ratios are one standard deviation below average. Furthermore, it suggests that banks’ demand curves for dollars become even more steep (inelastic) as their capital depletes. This finding complements that in Becker et al (2023), who find – using data on a specific form of bank lending, cross-country syndicated loans – that intermediation constraints influence FX dynamics.

Implications and conclusions

Our finding of inelastic USD demand by UK-resident global banks carries at least two key implications. First, in relative terms, the fact that the demand elasticity lies significantly below the supply elasticity implies that, due to their relative price insensitivity, UK-based banks exert greater influence over USD/GBP exchange-rate fluctuations in response to shocks than the (average) of the other financial intermediaries in the market. That is, UK-resident banks are a ‘marginal investor’ in the dollar-sterling market.

Second, inelastic USD demand by UK-resident banks implies that shifts in the supply of USD from the rest of the world – eg, from US monetary policy and other drivers of the Global Financial Cycle – can weigh heavily on the value of sterling vis-à-vis the dollar. This may imply larger effects on the macroeconomy via export and import prices. That being said, when banks are better capitalised, our results suggest that the extent of UK-resident banks’ inelasticity can be mitigated. Thus, domestic prudential policies (linked to capital ratios) could help to contribute to greater exchange-rate stability and thereby help insulate domestic economies from the Global Financial Cycle.

Simon Lloyd works in the Bank’s Monetary Policy Outlook Division, Daniel Ostry works in the Bank’s Global Analysis Division and Balduin Bippus is a PhD student at the University of Cambridge.

If you want to get in touch, please email us atbankunderground@bankofengland.co.ukor leave a comment below.

Commentswill only appear once approved by a moderator, and are only published where a full name is supplied. Bank Underground is a blog for Bank of England staff to share views that challenge – or support – prevailing policy orthodoxies. The views expressed here are those of the authors, and are not necessarily those of the Bank of England, or its policy committees.

Share the post “The granular origins of exchange-rate fluctuations”

The granular origins of exchange-rate fluctuations – Bank Underground (2024)

FAQs

What are the causes of fluctuation in exchange rates? ›

Factors that affect the exchange rate include but aren't limited to economic standing, speculation, stock market performance, political stability, current account status, terms of trade, and government debt.

What is the meaning of fluctuation in exchange rate? ›

Exchange rate fluctuations occur when foreign currencies undergo changes in value. Because each currency's value changes due to a variety of economic factors, any currency can be bought or sold for a different amount of another currency at any given time.

How do exchange rate fluctuations affect the profitability of companies? ›

For entrepreneurs, changes in exchange rates affect their businesses in two main ways: by changing the cost of supplies that are purchased from a different country, and by changing the attractiveness of their products to overseas customers.

What will happen if the exchange rate fluctuates? ›

When exchange rates change, the prices of imported goods will change in value, including domestic products that rely on imported parts and raw materials. Exchange rates also impact investment performance, interest rates, and inflation—and can even extend to influence the job market and real estate sector.

Why are exchange rates different at banks? ›

In order to make a profit, banks and other money changers use different rates for buying and selling currency. The online rates you see are probably mid-rates - half-way between the buying and selling rates. Of course, just to be on the safe side, banks also charge commission on the transaction...

What is one factor causing fluctuation in the exchange rate? ›

Numerous factors influence exchange rates, including a country's economic performance, the outlook for inflation, interest rate differentials, capital flows and so on. A currency's exchange rate is typically determined by the strength or weakness of the underlying economy.

How do you deal with exchange rate fluctuations? ›

Exchange rate risk cannot be avoided altogether when investing overseas, but it can be mitigated considerably through the use of hedging techniques. The easiest solution is to invest in hedged investments such as hedged ETFs. The fund manager of a hedged ETF can hedge forex risk at a relatively lower cost.

How often do exchange rates fluctuate? ›

Exchange rates constantly go up and down, fluctuating any number of times throughout the day.

Why is dollar rate fluctuating? ›

Currency valuations fluctuate constantly, driven by the flow of funds between markets. The two biggest drivers are central bank policies (interest rates set by the U.S. Federal Reserve and its counterparts in Europe, England, Japan and elsewhere); and economic growth relative to inflation.

What is the strongest currency in the world? ›

The Kuwaiti dinar (KWD) is the world's strongest currency, and this is for a number of reasons. For starters, Kuwait has one of the largest oil reserves in the world.

What type of risk relates to fluctuations in exchange rates? ›

Foreign exchange risk, also known as exchange rate risk, is the risk of financial impact due to exchange rate fluctuations. In simpler terms, foreign exchange risk is the risk that a business' financial performance or financial position will be impacted by changes in the exchange rates between currencies.

How to make a currency stronger? ›

Higher interest rates in a country can increase the value of that country's currency relative to nations offering lower interest rates. Political and economic stability and the demand for a country's goods and services are also prime factors in currency valuation.

Why are exchange rates so difficult to predict? ›

6 For a forecaster who must predict the future exchange rate, the conclusion seems to be as follows: It would be difficult to make any prediction using only information on macroeconomic variables such as the money supplies, income levels, interest rates, and inflation rates.

What drives currency fluctuations? ›

One of the main factors that can cause currency fluctuation is inflation. When a country experiences high inflation, its currency becomes less valuable because it can buy fewer goods and services. This makes it less attractive to investors, and the demand for that currency decreases, causing its value to drop.

What are the factors causing the exchange rate to change? ›

What drives exchange rates? Exchange rates are constantly moving, based on supply and demand. Whether one currency is in higher demand than another, depends on the perceived value of owning it, either to pay for goods and services, or as an investment.

What is a key reason why a country's exchange rate will fluctuate? ›

Currency exchange rates are constantly fluctuating, they follow a simple economics theory based on supply and demand. Most of the currencies are bought and sold based on flexible exchange rates, meaning their prices fluctuate based on the supply and demand in the foreign exchange market.

What might cause the exchange rate to rise? ›

Interest rates

To make the investment, they need to convert their money into the country's currency, which is known as a capital flow. Foreign direct investment increases a country's capital flow, leading to higher demand for its currency and causing the exchange rate to rise.

What causes change in real exchange rate? ›

Persistent changes in terms of trade (such as oil producers usually experience) and differences in fiscal policies, tariffs, and even financial development can also help explain why REERs can differ across countries.

Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Ms. Lucile Johns

Last Updated:

Views: 5949

Rating: 4 / 5 (41 voted)

Reviews: 80% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Ms. Lucile Johns

Birthday: 1999-11-16

Address: Suite 237 56046 Walsh Coves, West Enid, VT 46557

Phone: +59115435987187

Job: Education Supervisor

Hobby: Genealogy, Stone skipping, Skydiving, Nordic skating, Couponing, Coloring, Gardening

Introduction: My name is Ms. Lucile Johns, I am a successful, friendly, friendly, homely, adventurous, handsome, delightful person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.