Markets on edge as central banks walk the inflation tightrope (2024)

This was published 2 years ago

Opinion

Stephen Bartholomeusz

One of the peculiar out-workings of the belated central bank recognition that the surge in worldwide inflation rates was proving stickier than they anticipated has been the impact on an even more peculiar phenomenon. The amount of bonds with negative interest rates has plummeted.

Even before the pandemic the central bankers’ efforts to boost growth and, perversely, inflation rates through negligible policy rates and continuation of the asset purchases they had initiated in response to the 2008 financial crisis had resulted in the seemingly bizarre outcome of financial institutions and investors paying central banks to safeguard their money.

Markets on edge as central banks walk the inflation tightrope (1)

In 2019 there were more than $US10 trillion (about $14 trillion at the time) of bonds, including some corporate debt, with negative yields.

The response to the pandemic – almost every major central bank cut their policy rate (their versions of the Reserve Bank’s cash rate) to close to zero and embarked on a new round of asset purchases – saw that pool of negative-yielding bonds soar to about $US17 trillion.

With inflation raging in the major economies – it’s above 7 per cent in the US, five per cent in Europe and is 3.5 per cent and rising in Australia – and the central banks foreshadowing rate rises and the end to their asset purchases, that pool has been shrinking. Late last month it was just under $US10 trillion.

Then last week the US Federal Reserve Board’s confirmed its belated and abrupt conversion from dove to hawk. The European Central Bank also signalled late last week that rate rises are on its horizon and that its pandemic boost to asset purchases – it has been buying more than 100 per cent of European government bond issues – might end.

Loading

Those shifts in stance from the two key central banks saw the value of bonds with negative yields tumble from about $US9 trillion to $US5 trillion.

Germany’s 10-year bund yields, which had just lifted above zero, for the first time since early 2019, in the final days of last month, “shot up” to 0.23 per cent last week. Its five-year yields broke through zero per cent for the first time since 2018.

Advertisem*nt

Australia 10-year bond yields started the year at 1.67 per cent (having traded at less than half that when the pandemic first erupted in 2020) have climbed from 1.87 per cent to 2 per cent this month, their highest level since early 2019.

While that might not be good news for bond investors (bond prices fall as yields rise) it signals that central banks are finally getting what they once wished for – inflation – albeit that there is a risk that they might receive too much of a good thing.

It was the absence of inflation at sustainable pre-2008 rates and the low growth, productivity and business investment its absence signalled that created the historically aberrational pre-pandemic monetary settings.

Despite the unconventional settings, those policies had proved less than effective, with the floods of ultra-cheap liquidity pouring into financial assets – including negatively-yielding government and corporate bonds – rather than into productive investment or increased wages.

The same holds true, to an extent, for the even more expansive response of the central banks to the pandemic. They have poured near-costless liquidity into their systems.

The volume of money floating around in the US financial system, for instance, has swollen from less than $US16 trillion pre-pandemic to more than $US21 trillion today.

In most of the key economies, however, economic growth has picked up to levels not seen since 2008, despite the pandemic – or perhaps because of governments and central banks’ responses to it. There are even signs of wages growth.

Policymakers, and central bankers in particular, have an opportunity to shape the outcomes they have sought since 2008, where there is growth and low unemployment with moderate inflation.

Current inflation levels are unsustainable. When the US consumer price index is released on Thursday it is expected to show another increase, to about 7.3 per cent.

While the European Central Bank president, Christine Lagarde, has referred to “unanimous concern” within the bank over Europe’s 5.1 per cent inflation rate and investors are pricing in an end to bond purchases and a rate rise by mid-year, Lagarde has also said the chances of inflation stabilising at the ECB’s longstanding target of about two per cent (which is similar to the other major central banks) have increased.

The ECB is like the Fed and an even more cautious RBA. It believes the inflation rate will remain higher for longer than it previously thought but doesn’t believe it will remain at or above current levels for any great length of time and force a more draconian monetary policy response.

In some respects, that’s also the financial markets’ expectation.

Markets on edge as central banks walk the inflation tightrope (2)

Shorter term rates have spiked but a flattening yield curve signals that bond investors see inflation rates moderating in the medium term as the big driver of the surge in global inflation, the supply chain bottlenecks, gradually gets resolved.

There is a lot of money, however, parked on the sidelines. A lot of the cheap liquidity the Fed and its peers pumped into their financial systems wasn’t deployed in anything productive but has been deposited in financial institutions’ accounts at the central banks. There’s also vast amounts of government pandemic-inspired largesse sitting in household bank accounts.

If those funds were to be unfrozen and added a big surge in demand to the squeeze on supply the elevated inflation rates wouldn’t be transitory.

It’s impossible to tell at this point whether the pandemic and the central bank and government responses to it have enabled the major economies to sustainably break out of the low-growth, low-inflation malaise they’ve experienced since 2008.

Loading

If unsustainable inflation rates persist the central banks will have to raise rates faster and further than they now contemplate, killing off growth – and probably sparking mayhem in financial markets – in the process.

Policymakers, and central bankers in particular, have an opportunity to shape the outcomes they have sought since 2008, where there is growth and low unemployment with moderate inflation.

The surge in market interest rates this month, however, suggests investors think they won’t move quickly enough and will have to tighten their monetary policies so aggressively they will not just kill inflation, but growth.

The Market Recap newsletter is a wrap of the day’s trading. Get it each weekday afternoon.

,

register

or subscribe

to save articles for later.

License this article

  • Interest rates
  • Opinion
  • Bonds
  • Australian Government Treasury Bonds
  • Inflation

Most Viewed in Business

Loading

Markets on edge as central banks walk the inflation tightrope (2024)

FAQs

Are central banks causing inflation? ›

Because central banks could not lower short-term interest rates much below zero, they were constrained in their ability to expand monetary policy. Now, with higher rates, they have more room to cut rates to stimulate their economies, boosting inflation.

How does the central bank control inflation? ›

By maintaining expected inflation equal to its inflation target, money and inflation grow in line with the inflation target. By maintaining the real rate of interest equal to the natural rate, the central bank prevents monetary emissions that force undesired changes in prices.

Why do central banks target 2% inflation? ›

To keep inflation low and stable, the Government sets us an inflation target of 2%. This helps everyone plan for the future. If inflation is too high or it moves around a lot, it's hard for businesses to set the right prices and for people to plan their spending.

What is inflation targeting holding the line? ›

In this framework, a central bank estimates and makes public a projected, or “target,” inflation rate and then attempts to steer actual inflation toward that target, using such tools as interest rate changes.

Why is central banking bad? ›

Poor central banking policies ultimately lead to governments outspending their own budget constraints. Irresponsible monetary policies diminish purchasing power, which often causes crippling hyperinflation, as had famously occurred in countries like Argentina, Hungary, Zimbabwe, and pre-WWII Germany.

What does the central bank do when inflation is high? ›

When inflation is too high, the Federal Reserve typically raises interest rates to slow the economy and bring inflation down. When inflation is too low, the Federal Reserve typically lowers interest rates to stimulate the economy and move inflation higher.

How to reverse inflation? ›

Monetary policy: in monetary policy central bank generally increases the interest rate that reduces investment and economic growth. That reverses the inflation. 2. Money supply: taking money out of the market by central bank affect the consumption and demand, that decreases inflation.

Why is inflation so hard to stop? ›

There are a variety of reasons why it is hard to control inflation. When prices are higher, workers demand higher pay. When workers receive higher pay, they are able to afford more goods, which increases demand, which then increases prices, which can lead to a possible wage-price spiral.

What are three things the central bank can do to fight inflation? ›

The Fed has several tools it traditionally uses to tame inflation. It usually uses open market operations (OMO), the federal funds rate, and the discount rate in tandem.

Is deflation good or bad? ›

Typically, deflation is a sign of a weakening economy. Economists fear deflation because falling prices lead to lower consumer spending, which is a major component of economic growth. Companies respond to falling prices by slowing down their production, which leads to layoffs and salary reductions.

Why is 2 inflation better than 0? ›

Why has the inflation target been set at 2%, rather than at 0%? A price growth rate of 2% is low enough to fully reap the benefits of price stability and, at the same time, it provides a margin to reduce the risk of deflation.

Where did 2% inflation come from? ›

The 2 percent target widely adopted by central banks today originated from New Zealand, and surprisingly it came not from any academic study, but rather from an offhand comment during a television interview. During the late 1980s, New Zealand was going through a period of high inflation.

Who sets the inflation target? ›

Inflation targeting is straightforward, at least in theory. The central bank forecasts the future path of inflation and compares it with the target inflation rate (the rate the government believes is appropriate for the economy).

Does high inflation signal a recession? ›

Inflation can cause a recession in some instances, such as: If inflation spurs consumers to cut spending too much. Less money in the economy means lower revenues and potentially negative growth for businesses. If the Fed raises interest rates too much to rein in inflation.

Which countries use inflation targeting? ›

Countries
CountryCentral bankYear adopted inflation targeting
GeorgiaNational Bank of Georgia01/2009
Serbia, Republic ofNational Bank of Serbia01/2009
United StatesFederal Reserve01/2012
JapanBank of Japan01/2013
30 more rows

Why are central banks worried about inflation? ›

Investors appear to trust that data-dependent central banks will ease monetary policy when inflation decelerates further. But if inflation remains high, such lofty expectations could topple, which could lead to a correlated selloff of assets, from bonds to stocks to crypto assets.

Why are central banks so concerned about inflation expectations? ›

In the extreme, this process can increase the risk of deflation, a damaging economic condition in which prices fall over time rather than rise. Another reason that the Fed worries about low inflation expectations is that they are closely related to interest rates.

What central banks reduce inflation? ›

Central banks have a primary task of pursuing price stability. They do so by issuing different forms of money, setting an array of interest rates, and managing their balance sheets.

Why do central banks aim to keep inflation low? ›

For example, if there is an unanticipated increase in inflation, the value of savings goes down and the value of debt goes down, which transfers wealth from savers to borrowers. It decreases the volatility of inflation, which in turn lowers uncertainty and market interest rates and this motivates people to invest.

Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Rubie Ullrich

Last Updated:

Views: 6434

Rating: 4.1 / 5 (72 voted)

Reviews: 95% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Rubie Ullrich

Birthday: 1998-02-02

Address: 743 Stoltenberg Center, Genovevaville, NJ 59925-3119

Phone: +2202978377583

Job: Administration Engineer

Hobby: Surfing, Sailing, Listening to music, Web surfing, Kitesurfing, Geocaching, Backpacking

Introduction: My name is Rubie Ullrich, I am a enthusiastic, perfect, tender, vivacious, talented, famous, delightful person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.