Carbon tax v cap-and-trade: which is better? (2024)

Economists argue that, if the market is left to operate freely, greenhouse gas emissions will be excessive, since there is insufficient incentive for firms and households to reduce emissions. As such, they recommend applying the polluter pays principle and placing a price on carbon dioxide and other greenhouse gases. This can be implemented either through a carbon tax (known as a price instrument) or a cap-and-trade scheme (a so-called quantity instrument).

A carbon tax imposes a tax on each unit of greenhouse gas emissions and gives firms (and households, depending on the scope) an incentive to reduce pollution whenever doing so would cost less than paying the tax. As such, the quantity of pollution reduced depends on the chosen level of the tax. The tax is set by assessing the cost or damage associated with each unit of pollution and the costs associated with controlling that pollution. Getting the tax level right is key: too low and firms and households are likely to opt for paying the tax and continuing to pollute, over and above what is optimal for society. Too high and the costs will rise higher than necessary to reduce emissions, impacting on profits, jobs and end consumers.

By contrast, a cap-and-trade system sets a maximum level of pollution, a cap, and distributes emissions permits among firms that produce emissions. Companies must have a permit to cover each unit of pollution they produce, and they can obtain these permits either through an initial allocation or auction, or through trading with other firms. Since some firms inevitably find it easier or cheaper to reduce pollution than others, trading takes place. Whilst the maximum pollution quantity is set in advance, the trading price of permits fluctuates, becoming more expensive when demand is high relative to supply (for example when the economy is growing) and cheaper when demand is lower (for example in a recession). A price on pollution is therefore created as a result of setting a ceiling on the overall quantity of emissions.

In certain idealized circ*mstances, carbon taxes and cap-and-trade have exactly the same outcomes, since they are both ways to price carbon. However, in reality they differ in many ways.

One difference is the way the two policies distribute the cost of reducing pollution. With cap-and-trade, it has often been the case that permits are given out for free initially (known as "grandfathering"). This means cheaper compliance for industry in the early stages of the scheme, because they only pay for any extra permits bought from other firms – not for the initial tranche of permits given to them to cover most of their emissions under 'business as usual'. This approach is obviously popular with industry and explains why grandfathering has been used, since it helps get firms to accept controls on emissions in the first place. By contrast, with a tax there is an immediate cost for businesses to pay on every unit of greenhouse gas produced, so there is a bigger initial hit to the balance sheet. But while grandfathering is better for near-term business profitability, it is not necessarily the best outcome for society. Indeed, it deprives the government of valuable revenues, which it could raise in auctioning the permits initially, and which could be used to reduce other taxes.

The mechanisms also differ in how they perform under uncertainty about the costs and benefits of reducing emissions. Under a tax, the price of emitting a unit of pollution is set, but the total quantity of emissions is not. Therefore a tax ensures everyone knows the price being paid (at least for the immediate future) for each unit of carbon dioxide emitted, but uncertainty remains about the actual quantity of emissions. Conversely, cap-and-trade provides certainty about the quantity of emissions (it cannot exceed the cap), but uncertainty about the cost of achieving these reductions. Which is preferred depends on how sensitive the level of environmental damage is to changes in emissions, compared with how sensitive the cost of reducing pollution is to the same changes. If the level of environmental damage is more sensitive, then it is important to be sure what the quantity of emissions is, which points to cap-and-trade. Conversely if the cost of reducing pollution is more highly sensitive to changes in emissions, it is better to be sure about the cost of cutting emissions, pointing to a tax.

What this means for climate change policy is debated. In the short term, most economists agree that uncertainty alone argues for a tax. Climate change depends on the stock of greenhouse gases in the atmosphere, and in each year the increase in that stock due to new emissions is small, so the environment is probably not that sensitive to the uncertainty about the level of emissions brought about by choosing a tax, at least over a year or two. On the other side of the ledger, the cost of reducing pollution is highly sensitive to changes in emissions, since it can be expensive to businesses to change their production methods abruptly. In the long term, however, it is less clear whether a tax is preferable, because big changes in the stock of greenhouse gases in the atmosphere may cause substantial environmental damage.

Some economists recommend a hybrid model that may offer the best of both worlds. This tends to comprise of a cap on emissions (to regulate the quantity of pollution), but with adjustment mechanisms such as a carbon price floor or ceiling, to keep the price of a permit within acceptable bounds. Hybrid schemes have their own problems, however, such as greater complexity and more intervention by the regulator in the permit market.

Whichever of these policies is favoured to place a price on carbon, they represent just one of a number of policies needed to cut greenhouse gas emissions.

This article was written by Luca Taschini, Simon Dietz and Naomi Hicks of the Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment at LSE in collaboration with the Guardian

The ultimate climate change FAQ

This answer last updated: 28.01.2013
Read about the project and suggest a question
Report an error in this answer

Related questions
Why does climate change get described as a 'stock-flow' problem?
What is the 'polluter pays' principle?
What is a carbon price and why do we need one?

This editorial is free to reproduce under Creative Commons


This post by The Guardian is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-No Derivative Works 2.0 UK: England & Wales License.
Based on a work at theguardian.com

Carbon tax v cap-and-trade: which is better? (2024)

FAQs

Carbon tax v cap-and-trade: which is better? ›

Carbon Taxes Lend Predictability to Energy Prices.

Is cap-and-trade better than carbon tax? ›

Pros and cons

Cap-and-trade has one key environmental advantage over a carbon tax: It provides more certainty about the amount of emissions reductions that will result and little certainty about the price of emissions (which is set by the emissions trading market).

What is the difference between carbon trading and cap-and-trade? ›

A carbon tax directly establishes a price on greenhouse gas emissions—so companies are charged a dollar amount for every ton of emissions they produce—whereas a cap and trade program issues a set number of emissions “allowances” each year.

What major advantage does a carbon tax have over a cap & trade system when it comes to controlling the amount of carbon emissions? ›

A carbon tax differs from a cap-and-trade program in that it provides a higher level of certainty about cost, but not about the level of emission reduction to be achieved (cap and trade does the inverse).

Why is carbon tax better? ›

Not only does the tax discourage polluting activities, it also provides incentives for research, investment, and deployment of more efficient and low emission alternatives. It is one of the most effective ways to reduce emissions.

Why carbon tax over cap-and-trade? ›

Carbon Taxes Lend Predictability to Energy Prices.

In contrast, a cap-and-trade program will exacerbate the volatility of energy prices since the price of carbon allowances will fluctuate as weather and economic factors affect the demand for energy.

Why is cap-and-trade more efficient? ›

Trading can lead to cuts in pollution sooner

Because there are only so many allowances available, total pollution drops as the cap falls. As companies use established techniques to lower emissions, such as adopting energy-efficient technology, entrepreneurs see opportunity.

Does the US have carbon cap-and-trade? ›

RGGI is the first mandatory cap-and-trade program in the United States to limit carbon dioxide emissions from the power sector. California's program was the first multi-sector cap-and-trade program in North America.

Does cap-and-trade reduce emissions? ›

The Cap-and-Trade Program is a key element of California's strategy to reduce greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions.

Why do economists prefer carbon tax? ›

Leading scientists and economists support a carbon price because it works fast to reduce pollution. Businesses support a carbon price because it drives innovation that will transform our economy, creating jobs and putting millions of Americans back to work.

Who benefits from carbon trading? ›

Carbon credits also provides various co-benefits to local communities where the projects are hosted, such as sustainable development through the creation of green jobs, sustainable energy, environmental and biodiversity protection, and climate adaptation and resilience.

How does a carbon tax boost the economy? ›

In addition to reducing emissions, a carbon tax could improve other economic incentives by reducing other tax rates or paying down the deficit (Parry and Williams 2011). A carbon tax could have other benefits too.

Why we shouldn't have a carbon tax? ›

“Increasing the cost of energy in the U.S. with a carbon tax merely incentivizes industry and those jobs to move to Asia where dirtier fuel is used without any environmental safeguards. This increases global emissions and weakens our economy,” said Dr. Cassidy.

What are the negatives of carbon tax? ›

Risks Competitiveness & Leakage

Major energy using industries often oppose carbon taxes, arguing they raise costs and undermine competitiveness, especially if nearby regions lack similar policies. Manufacturing could shift abroad, raising “carbon leakage” concerns.

Why is carbon tax not popular? ›

There are good reasons why governments may not want to use carbon taxes, and one of them relates to their welfare impacts. For example, a carbon tax on fossil fuels is often regressive in its impact- hurting poorer people relatively more than richer ones.

What is the difference between cap-and-trade and carbon pricing? ›

A carbon tax and cap-and-trade are opposite sides of the same coin. A carbon tax sets the price of carbon dioxide emissions and allows the market to determine the quantity of emission reductions. Cap-and-trade sets the quantity of emissions reductions and lets the market determine the price.

What are the disadvantages of cap-and-trade? ›

Critics of cap-and-trade point to problems that actual cap-and-trade programs like the European Union Emissions Trading Schedule and the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative have confronted, such as weak emissions caps, volatility in emissions allowance prices, and overly generous allocations of emissions allowances to ...

What are the pros and cons of carbon tax? ›

The carbon tax debate involves weighing the pros and cons of pricing carbon as a way to reduce greenhouse gas emissions and address climate change. While carbon tax can encourage the use of cleaner energy and provide a stable policy framework, it may also be regressive and face opposition from certain industries.

Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Cheryll Lueilwitz

Last Updated:

Views: 6598

Rating: 4.3 / 5 (74 voted)

Reviews: 81% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Cheryll Lueilwitz

Birthday: 1997-12-23

Address: 4653 O'Kon Hill, Lake Juanstad, AR 65469

Phone: +494124489301

Job: Marketing Representative

Hobby: Reading, Ice skating, Foraging, BASE jumping, Hiking, Skateboarding, Kayaking

Introduction: My name is Cheryll Lueilwitz, I am a sparkling, clean, super, lucky, joyous, outstanding, lucky person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.